All Ur Code Base r Belong to Us

by on January 29, 2007

Ryan Paul at Ars has a fantastic illustrated timeline of the Microsoft/Novell deal and the subsequent flamewar among tech companies. Here’s his conclusion:

Now that the steady stream of accusations has died down, the implications of the deal are beginning to become more apparent. Although Ballmer validated the critics’ concerns with unsubstantiated patent infringement claims, the claims themselves haven’t negatively affected Linux adoption. Microsoft has been making baseless claims about Linux since 2004, and it seems apparent at this point that few outside of the Linux community really take those claims seriously. It is ironic that the Linux community itself raised the profile of Ballmer’s patent infringement assertion and perpetuated its relevance with such a vehement response. Regardless of the motivations behind Ballmer’s actions, the most detrimental consequence of the entire deal and subsequent fallout is the fragmentation that has resulted from the prevailing divisive attitude that it has engendered in members of the Linux community.

The success of the Linux operating system is largely predicated on the collaboration of the Linux development community, and this petty squabbling impedes that collaboration. What the corporate executives of these companies have declared, with stentorian vehemence, is that they are all abundantly willing to abandon collaboration and take advantage of each other whenever it is convenient.

You should check out the rest of it for the pictures, if nothing else.

Telcos are Not Suicidal

by on January 27, 2007 · 12 comments

I’ve finished reading Bill Herman’s paper. It’s got a lot of interesting material in it, so I’ll be discussing it in several posts over the next few days.

Having finished the paper, I remain convinced that Herman hasn’t given much thought to the details of how the discriminatory pricing regime he envisions would actually work. He seems to imagine that AT&T can simply send Google a bill for ten million dollars and Google will whip out its checkbook and pay it. This, it seems to me, is highly improbable. To see why, let’s look at the other end of the market—the millions of tiny websites like this one that are only frequented by a few hundred people every day.

Continue reading →

Music Industry Booming

by on January 26, 2007

Via Mike, here’s an L.A. Times article on the thriving music industry. No, not the one represented by the RIAA, the other one:

While the U.S. recording industry continues to slide under pressure from illegal downloaders and file-sharers, the other side of the music world–businesses catering to those who create the music–has nearly doubled over the last decade to become a $7.5-billion industry. The key difference in their contrasting fortunes is a simple physical reality: You can’t download a tuba. But new technology has also been a boon: Digital home recording has played a large role in the industry’s growth and helped a new generation of hobbyist music-makers move out of the garage and onto the Internet.

As I’ve argued before, I think people overestimate the role of piracy in the long-term decline of the music industry. The fundamental problem is that their core competence–pressing and shipping little plastic disks around the country–is becoming increasingly obsolete. It’s true that piracy is accelerating their decline, but the decline would happen regardless, as musicians increasingly discover they don’t need to ship plastic disks around the country in order to get music to their fans.

But I think this illustrates the silliness of the thesis that the music industry is dying, from two perspectives. First, there’s the article’s main point that only some segments of the music industry are hurting, and those gains are largely being made up elsewhere. This suggests that there’s little reason for the average musician to be fearful–as music becomes more popular, there there will continue to be plenty of opportunities for teaching music lessons, giving live performances, etc.

But more fundamentally, I think this is a pretty powerful counter to the notion that musicians need to be paid to ensure we continue to have good music. The vast majority of the people purchasing musical instruments never intend to make a living at it. Many others hope they’ll be able to make a living at it, but realize full well that their odds are long. Yet millions of people still spend billions of dollars training to become better musicians. It’s awfully hard to see how strong copyright protection could explain this. More likely, most people make music because they enjoy making music. And they’ll continue doing so regardless of how copyright law is changed.

Thinking about Bill Herman’s argument that network discrimination threatens freedom of speech, and his broader point that broadband ISPs can use their control over the “last mile” to force Internet users to do or not do certain things (mostly, give them more money), it occurs to me that Hayek’s discussion of coercion in chapter 9 of The Constitution of Liberty has some relevance:

Coercion occurs when one man’s actions are made to serve another man’s will, not for his own but for the other’s purpose. It is not that the coerced does not choose at all; if that were the case, we should not speak of his “acting.” If my hand is guided by physical force to trace my signature or my finger pressed against the trigger of a gun, I have not acted. Such violence, which makes my body someone else’s tool, is of course, as bad as coercion proper and must be prevented for the same reason. Coercion implies, however, that I still choose but that my mind is made someone else’s tool, because the alternatives before me have been so manipulated that the conduct that the coercer wants me to choose becomes for me the least painful one.

Now, I should say at the outset that Hayek would not have regarded an ISP trying to manipulate its customers as coercion, as he was thinking about cases where a coercer was able to exert broad control over peoples’ lives through threats of violence. But I think that what Herman claims AT&T will do to Internet users is analogous (albeit much less severe) to Hayek’s description of how states can coerce their citizens.

Continue reading →

Every week, I look at a software patent that’s been in the news. You can see previous installments in the series here. This week, my starting point is this story reporting that one of National Instruments’ patents on its LabVIEW software has been upheld. I have not been able to determine for certain which patent was upheld, but I’ve arbitrarily chosen this one as a likely candidate. If anyone knows for sure which patent was upheld, or how I can look that up, please let me know.

Here’s the abstract for this week’s patent:

A method for programming a computer to execute a procedure, is based on a graphical interface which utilizes data flow diagrams to represent the procedure. The method stores a plurality of executable functions, scheduling functions, and data types. A data flow diagram is assembled in response to the user input utilizing icons which correspond to the respective executable functions, scheduling functions, and data types which are interconnected by arcs on the screen. A panel, representative of an instrument front panel having input and output formats is likewise assembled for the data flow diagram. An executable program is generated in response to the data flow diagram and the panel utilizing the executable functions, scheduling functions, and data types stored in the memory. Furthermore, the executable functions may include user defined functions that have been generated using the method for programming. In this manner, a hierarchy of procedures is implemented, each represented by a data flow diagram.

Continue reading →

Since I’ve been criticizing a paper opposing neutrality regulation lately, it seemed only fair to criticize the other side for a change. A reader wrote in to point out that Bill Herman has recently released a new version of his paper advocating neutrality regulations. Before I get started with my critique, I want to mention that I’ve interacted with Herman in the past, and he’s a smart and thoughtful guy. I didn’t find myself persuaded by his paper, but it’s a well-written and thorough argument for his position.

In this post, I’ll critique one of the two arguments he makes in parts II and III of the paper, in which he sketches out the dangers posed by network discrimination: the contention that without new regulations, ISPs will begin censoring Internet content. It seems to me that the paper demonstrates one of the same shortcomings I noted in the Hahn/Litan paper: although it talks a lot about network discrimination in the abstract, it’s extremely vague about the details of how such a regime would actually work.

Continue reading →

…because if so, someone’s gotta send him this link:

Hat tip: EFF

Also, I’m pleased to see that EFF are demanding hearings to ensure that the Bush administration is telling the truth when they claim they’re finally complying with the law.

Kahle and Orphan Works

by on January 25, 2007

I’ve got a new article up at Ars about the Ninth Circuit’s Kahle decision:

Kahle plans to appeal the ruling to a larger panel of the Ninth Circuit, but their prospects don’t look good. With three Ninth Circuit judges already ruling against him, Kahle will face an uphill battle convincing the full Ninth Circuit that his arguments are different from those the Supreme Court raised in Eldred.

That’s a shame, because Kahle’s lawsuit highlights a serious and growing problem. New technologies are greatly enhancing the opportunity to make better use of older creative works. Books that have traditionally sat unread on dusty library shelves can now be made available in searchable form via the Internet. Old films that once languished unwatched in vaults could be digitized and made available for consumers to view in their living rooms. The main thing standing in the way is copyright law.

If the courts ultimately reject Kahle’s arguments, the battle to free orphan works will shift back to Congress. Some scholars have suggested that Congress should enact an orphan works defense that would shield individuals who reproduced a copyrighted work after making a diligent effort to find the copyright holder. The UK’s Gowers Review has recommended that a similar rule be adopted in the European Union. Although this would not make orphan works as widely available as placing them in the public domain, it might be enough for the likes of Kahle and Google.

Since it was a quasi-news article, I didn’t spend much time discussing the case on the merits. Although I certainly hope they prevail, their argument didn’t strike me as terribly strong. And even if the courts are sympathetic to their argument on the legal merits, it’s hard to see what remedy the courts could fashion. They certainly can’t throw all works created between 1964 and 1977 into the public domain, nor could they realistically reinstate a registration system that’s atrophied over the last decade. About all they could conceivably due is rule that the works will fall into the public domain by some particular date unless Congress acts first to reinstate the registration system. But it seems unlikely that a Supreme Court that shied away from locking horns with Congress in Eldred would take the even more confrontational stance that’s urged in this case.

On Knowing Your Subject

by on January 25, 2007 · 2 comments

“Cog” at The Abstract Factory has a pretty damning critique of the Hahn/Litan paper’s citation of RFCs. He considers each of the four RFCs in turn and makes a pretty compelling argument that none of them say what Hahn and Litan say they say.

Before I get to Cog’s post, I should note that I was wrong in saying they didn’t cite the RFCs in question. There is, apparently, a short version and a long version of the paper, and I was looking at the shorter version, from which the footnotes are omitted. But they did offer them in the full version.

Anyway, I’ll just quote Cog’s comments on one of the four RFCs Hahn and Litan quote:

Continue reading →

Bad News for Apple

by on January 24, 2007 · 14 comments

From the Financial Times:

Apple was dealt a blow in Europe on Wednesday when Norway’s powerful consumer ombudsman ruled that its iTunes online music store was illegal because it did not allow downloaded songs to be played on rival technology companies’ devices.

The decision is the first time any jurisdiction has concluded iTunes breaks its consumer protection laws and could prompt other European countries to review the situation.

The ombudsman has set a deadline of October 1 for the Apple to make its codes available to other technology companies so that it abides by Norwegian law. If it fails to do so, it will be taken to court, fined and eventually closed down.

Apple, whose iTunes dominates the legal download market, has its proprietory system Fairplay. Songs and tunes downloaded through iTunes are designed to work with Apple’s MP3 player iPod, but cannot be played on rival devices.

Although I applaud the goal of increasing competition in the legal download market, I don’t think having Norwegian bureaucrats overseeing Apple’s software development process is a good solution. But as I’ve pointed out before: this should be a surprise. Regulatory schemes like the DMCA (and the EUCD in Europe) frequently have unintended consequences. And often, those unintended consequences are often cited as a justification for enacting more regulations to mitigate the harms caused by the previous round of regulation.

What we need, instead, is deregulation: Congress should repeal the anti-circumvention provisions of the DMCA, so that companies are free to reverse-engineer Apple’s products in order to build compatible devices.